AgTalk Home
AgTalk Home
Search Forums | Classifieds (4) | Skins | Language
You are logged in as a guest. ( logon | register )

Soybean LDP
View previous thread :: View next thread
   Forums List -> Market TalkMessage format
 
zenfarm
Posted 3/13/2017 08:33 (#5896084 - in reply to #5896019)
Subject: RE: Soybean LDP


South central kansas

What about productivity increases of crop production over that same time frame?.

The following is from the Farmdoc article(2013) looking at the ratio of farm prices paid(productivity adj.) and farm prices received for the US.



http://farmdocdaily.illinois.edu/2013/03/prices-paid-farm-inputs-received-crops.html

 


 Adjustment for Productivity

Farms can afford to pay more for inputs whose productivity has increased. Higher productivity means more output is generated per unit of input. To adjust for this consideration, the index of prices paid for U.S. farm inputs is divided by the total factor productivity of inputs used by the U.S. farm sector. As Figure 2 illustrates, this adjustment essentially results in crop prices and farm input prices largely tracking each other, thus eliminating the difference in their long term trends. In other words, the increasing productivity of farm inputs largely explains the larger increase in farm input prices relative to the prices paid to farms for crops. The finding also is consistent with the considerable time spent by business, management experts, and the farm media on helping farms understand technological change, especially as it relates to input productivity.


fig2.jpg


Summary Observations on Managing Risk and Farm Policy

To assist in understanding the implications of this analysis, Figure 2 is reconfigured as Figure 3. Figure 3 presents the ratio of crop prices to farm input prices adjusted for farm input productivity. To aid interpretation, this ratio is standardized by setting the average ratio over 1948 -2009 equal to 100%.

The higher is this ratio, the more favorable is the crop sector's economic situation. The highest ratios occur in 1973, 1974, and 1975, or during the prosperity of the 1970s. On the other hand, during the difficult economic times of the 1980s, most of the ratios were less than 100%. This period of economic difficulty is often seen as a response to the prosperity of the 1970s. In addition, Congress sharply increased support prices in the 1981 Farm Bill. This policy decision deferred needed adjustments by farms, thus prolonging the period of adjustment and perhaps made the adjustment even worse. Currently, many farm groups support large increases in U.S. target prices in the next farm bill. If such increases come into existence, it will be interesting to see if similar consequences occur.

Over the period of this analysis no trend exists in the ratio of crop output prices to farm input prices adjusted for input productivity. A linear trend explains less than 1% of the variation in the ratio. Moreover, from 1948 through 1972 the ratio averaged 99%, exactly the same as since 1996.

Since 1948, major changes have occurred in the U.S. crop sector and the U.S. farm safety net. Prior to 1972, U.S. crop farms were much smaller than today and a large share also raised livestock. U.S. farm policy consisted of price supports fixed at levels above market clearing prices, implemented via large acreage set asides and large public stocks. Since 1996, the U.S. has had no acreage set asides, few public stocks, and no floor on prices. The similarity in the ratio of crop output prices to farm input prices adjusted for input productivity throughout these major changes suggests that the ultimate beneficiaries of extended farm safety net support are the providers of farm inputs. Agricultural economists have long focused on the price of land as a beneficiary of farm programs, but Figure 3 suggests providers of all inputs may benefit. The simple explanation is that extended farm supports improve the ability to buy inputs, which results in higher input prices.

Figure 3 thus calls into question the wisdom of a farm safety net that provides extended support to U.S. farms. If U.S. society desire to help U.S. farms through periods of economic stress, temporary supports that phase out are preferable. Supports that phase out will not translate into higher input prices. Higher input prices reduce the international competitiveness of U.S. farms and raise the cost of U.S. farm products to U.S. consumers. However, as Figure 3 also illustrates, there were 3 periods in which the ratio remained below 100% for 6 consecutive years: 1967-1972, 1978-1983, and 1998-2003. Thus, the period of adjustment will likely extend beyond the 1-year time window of the current crop insurance program. The same conclusion was reached in the farmdoc post on the persistence of low and high farm prices, available here.


fig3.jpg<



Edited by zenfarm 3/13/2017 08:49
Top of the page Bottom of the page


Jump to forum :
Search this forum
Printer friendly version
E-mail a link to this thread

(Delete cookies)